On the private provision of public goods
The main idea: allowing the private provision of some public services by peculiarities in contract design.
0. Posts on this blog are ranked in decreasing order of likeability to myself. This entry was originally posted on 27.11.2022, and the current version may have been updated several times from its original form.
0.1 This is an expanded and translated version of what I’ve
written elsewhere for the specific application of city parking. I think it
generalises pretty well.
1 The problem
1.1 Assume you wish to provide a service that is beleaguered
by positive externalities to the degree that no private provider would ever
fund the service, as they could only capture a small part of the true value it
would provide.
1.2 An immediate example would be a rail line between two
major cities, which increases the property values in both by orders of magnitude
more than you can ever charge by way of ticketing. As I’m using this as just an
example, ignore the obvious solution of selling the line plus land around the
stations here, as similar solutions do not come by as easily in other
applications.
1.3 If you’d like to avoid the public operation of the line
for reasons of well-known inefficiencies, a first-order solution would be to
build the line publicly and then auction it off to the highest bidder, so that
the actual operation is private. Given the discrepancy between true value and
ticketing revenue, the sale would most likely be a loss-making operation, but (within
broad limits) profits are not the point for the public purse which can capture
part of the true value of the line through taxes.
1.4 The problem with this solution though is the inverse
relationship between ridership and total (inc. externalities) value, whereby
the more you charge in tickets, the less the ridership, and the greater the
impact on the positive externality.
1.5 Fully privatizing the line could well result in a
profit-maximising owner setting such prices as to leave part of the capacity
unused (classic monopoly problem), as long as the total revenue is maximised.
Nothing wrong with this in principle, but in such application the real value is
the unseen, not the ticketing revenue, and such a real but unseen value of the
line is majorly impacted.
1.6 Examples that could be argued to fit this model include
(off the top of my head) public transport, road infrastructure, sewage and
energy transmission systems, city parking and quite a few more.
1.7 What all of these scenarios have in common is that there
seems to be no way to calculate the real value-maximising price and quantity
mix, but the answer feels like its lower and higher respectively than what a
private provider would find in their interest to go for.
1.8 We can still provide such services privately though if we take care to construct an appropriate mix of incentives for such a private provider. Neither of the two ideas floated below is a fully satisfactory solution to the issues caused by extensive externalities, as neither allows for the market to calculate the quantity of the service that is offered. Still, both allow the calculation of an efficient price for a pre-set quantity, and thus I’d argue that they - and especially the second proposal - are still major steps in direction of the efficient provision of public goods.
2 The first, less satisfactory solution
2.1 Keeping with the rail example, you build the rail line
publicly and then auction it off to private operators. But bids are not
solicited in the form of prices to pay (indeed, no price will be paid for the
acquisition at all) but instead of prices that the provider will charge to the
public: the lowest price wins. A pre-set portion of the revenue is paid back to
the government, which can be packaged into a bond format and sold off
separately to the broader market.
2.2 In theory, bidders have an incentive to bid the price
that matches the sum of their operations cost, market profit rate and portion
withheld by the government, with the winner being he who can operate the line
at the lowest cost. No one would price such as to leave unused capacity (empty
seats) except as dictated by operations cost.
2.3 A major issue with the model would be the tendency for
people to overestimate how efficiently they can run the line, with the process
resulting in a bankrupt provider a few years down the path. A closely related
point is the lack of flexibility, as once you set the winning (lowest) price,
there is no way to change it even though conditions change all the time.
2.4 You could have the winner buy back in the open market
all bonds issued under 2.1, thus giving them the option to set whichever price
they’d like, but this could be an expensive endeavour for a provider who’d be
strapped for cash almost by design.
2.5 Further, once you do this and buy back the liability,
the whole unorthodox contract design becomes good for nothing, and the issue
with potential overcharging emerges again.
2.6 I don’t have a solution to this major issue, which is
why this approach is my least favourite, as it seems to be ill suited to
long-term operations.
2.7 Other minor issues would be the challenge of determining
who among the bidders is actually providing the lowest price, as in practice
there are dozens of types of tickets available: peak, day off-peak, night,
pre-paid, etc. Which option is to be compared?
2.8 The issue would probably be ameliorated to a reasonable degree by having bids be public and giving bidders the option to change their submission as many times as needed within the bidding window, which I’d expect would lead to bids being continuously adjusted towards a market optimum. So, not a huge issue but worth mentioning.
3 The second, more satisfactory solution
3.1 Soldiering on with the rail example, you build the rail
line publicly and then auction it off to private providers, in a normal auction
where the highest price provided to you wins. But the contract stipulates a minimum
capacity (the actual seating capacity of the line) and any part of this being
found empty (allegedly on account of overpricing) would cause the operator to
pay to the government the price of that empty seat: you pay me the ticket of
any empty seats on the train (see 3.61 on the number of seats thus contracted for). In the same fashion as before, this liability is
packaged in a bond format and sold off separately.
3.2 If we assume X to be the price that would maximise the
revenue of the operator whilst leaving some capacity empty, and X - Y to be the
price that ensures full occupancy of the railcars, I’d expect the winner to
charge X - some portion of Y, if not X - Y in full.
3.3 The same minor issue as earlier applies, with it not
being immediately obvious which price the operator is to pay back for an empty
seat (pre-paid or at-the-gate ticket), but here this is an even more minor
issue, with a solution just needing to be specified in advance.
3.4 Another minor issue would be the need for some sort of
real-time measure of occupancy, not a huge challenge in this day and age, I
think.
3.5 Otherwise, note how this design is much more flexible
than the previous one, where the operator has full rights to amend their prices
as they see fit, allowing for long-term operation and true ownership of the
line.
3.6 Indeed, the design could be a bit too flexible, as the
operator could still go out and buy back the bond issued under 3.1 if this is
the profit-maximising move, thus invalidating the whole point of the design.
I’m not sure whether allowing or disallowing this would be optimal.
3.61 Yet a further bit of flexibility could be engineered by allowing the bidders under 3.1 to bid a combination of purchase price and guaranteed quantities, to see if there's and obvious inflection point at some quantity other than foreseen by the government. Maybe 500 passengers per day on the line connecting two villages is a bit unfeasible, eh?
3.7 It is worth noting that you could, in principle, run a
fully socialist economy in this way, with the state building everything and
setting production quantities by five-year plans and outsourcing the efficient
operation of the plan to the market. It’d still be a mess in terms of
calculation as you still set quantities centrally, but the prices being charged
would be much closer to optimal and meaningful.
3.8 In principle, reliance on the prices could even lead to
the gradual improvement of the quantities scheduled in time, in a matter
similar to - but probably much better behaved than - what was foreseen by
market socialism.
3.9 Indeed, the open trade of bonds as per 3.1 would appear
to give this economy the chance to organically privatise itself, or portions
thereof.
3.10 I’d think a bit more about the implications of such an economy if I didn’t have a better option for those elites who seek socialism. Except that a heavily-modified version of this mechanism could conceivably be used to manage virtual companies set up within a business large enough that internal accounting is not quite able to calculate on the basis of rational prices.
Comments
Post a Comment